Wednesday, February 27, 2008

$200 Million B.C. 2010 Olympic Bursary Program would be a Golden Opportunity for Gordon Campbell

The new $350 million Canada Student Grant Program announced in this week's federal budget is a far cry from the $2 billion shared cost program advocated on this blog site a couple of weeks ago. It is, however, a step in the right direction. It could also be just the springboard that Premier Campbell needs in order to rectify one of the more unfortunate legacies of his first six years in office, B.C.'s high student debt (on average, $27,000 over four years). And to do one better than both the NDP and the Federal Government when it comes to funding our universities. Here is how it would work:

*$200 million dollars would be distributed to the 100,000 neediest full-time students in the province, and a fraction of that $2,000 allotment per student would also be available on a sliding scale to less needy and part-time students. This would be a tied demand-side subsidy that could be applied either to pay down Canada Student Loans or to pay tuition fees

* A maximum of $50 million dollars, or one-quarter of the amount, could be allowed to flow through to the colleges and universities in the form of higher tuition fees--up to approximately $100 per 3-unit semester course. This would have the advantage of not robbing Peter to pay Paul as historically has often been the case when tuition freezes have occurred at the expense of university revenue-raising capacity, or when tuition increases have been allowed without compensating student aid. It would also have the further advantage of being a demand-side source of revenue rather than just a grant given by government to universities. This revenue would be controlled by student consumers, thereby serving as an additional incentive for universities to be sensitive to student needs, for example by providing more popular and effective teaching. It would also prove to be a more equitable allottment in its incidence than the typical supply side grant, for the reasons cited in the previous posting. If there is a concern about the cost to non-bursary students, a fraction of the bursary could be extended on a pro-rata basis to wealthier students and/or part-time students (as mentioned above), or the higher tuition fee per course could be limited to bursary-holders.

* When combined with the $800 or $2000 per student federal grant, such a program could make a significant dent in student debt loads--and a sizeable contribution to improving access to BC's post-secondary institutions without compromising their quality.

* What better way to commemorate the 2010 Olympics and herald BC's bright future than with a direct investment in our human capital infrastructure as significant as our governments' many comparable investments in physical infrastructure ---with the BC 2010 Olympic Bursary?

Saturday, February 02, 2008

NDP deserves a B for their new post-secondary aid policy

Recent B.C. premiers have deserved failing grades on the issue of post-secondary funding. When premier and Minister for Youth Glen Clark obliged student demands for a tuition fee freeze, he helped accessibility but at the cost of compounding a revenue shortfall for our universities. When Gordon Campbell heard the universities' cry for financial help by relaxing the ceiling on tuition fees, plus making a few well-publicized funding announcements, he damaged student accessiblity to the point that British Columbia now leads the nation in student loan debt per capita, at $27,000 for a four-year program ($3,000 above the Canadian average).

The most basic lesson from both the Clark and the Campbell years is therefore fairly obvious.That is, a policy that focuses on regulating or deregulating the price of higher education is really only half a policy: any government that simply addresses accessiblity through price controls damages the quality of universities, just as any government that simply deregulates tuition without a concomitant policy for student incomes damages access and equality of opportunity.

As a university professor from a working-class family, I am particularly attuned to the latter point. I often think that the 1970s and 1980s represented a high point for equality of opportunity in our society, at least for white males. But besides the barriers posed by tuition fees and the cost of living is a more hidden source of inequity: the highly regressive character of the funding formulas that are typically used to allocated funds to recipient universities. Since public universities are typically funded out of consolidated revenues (on a per-student basis), and because children of higher socio-economic groups are disproportionately represented in universities, the system of flat-based funding represents a regressive transfer from poorer to more affluent families. As Nicolas Barr puts it, "the taxes of poor families contribute to the consumption by the rich of a university education which helps to keep them rich." (The Economics of the Welfare State, 3rd edn Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1998, p.324)

There are also numerous efficiency and quality arguments against such a reliance upon supply-side funding. Public universities have difficulty competing with elite private institutions for the best faculty and the highest levels of research funding; lower tuition fees are linked with higher drop-out rates, perhaps explaining why Quebec has not realized great improvements in access despite having very low tuition fees. And, as no less an authority than Adam Smith once observed, "Beyond some point the higher level of endowment to any university, the lower its efficiency."

But wait a minute--if supply-side funding out of general consolidated revenue is both inequitable and inefficient, doesn't that imply greater reliance on demand-side funding? And doesn't that mean--gulp--higher tuition fees? Yup. But that need not be a barrier to access, provided there is a generous income-contingent grant -and -loan program, or tied demand-side subsidy that is targetted to tuition fees. I suggest that at the federal level there be a $2 billion national tuition voucher scheme, giving a tuition voucher up to $5,000 annually to the 400,000 neediest students , as based on family income and/or existing debt load, that would both significantly reduce average student loan debt and simultaneously increase university revenues. It would differ from both existing policy and the NDP platform in that it would allow universities greater latitude to compete for students on the basis of quality (paid for by higher fees, up to a voucher-related limit) as well as on the basis of price.

It is good to see the BC NDP get away from its Clark-era fixation on simply controlling tuition fees, and it is great to see a leading political party proposing to do something about interest costs on student debt. But the NDP also needs to recognize that the purpose of increased university funding is not that it allows universities to reduce their reliance upon tuition income, in favour of even greater reliance on inequitable and inefficient supply side funding. A good balance between demand-side and supply side revenues will have benefits for efficiency, quality, and flexibility on the part of universities and choice as well as equitable access for students.